Abstract
Energy equity refers to the condition in which access to the cleaner energy required by individuals is equally available to all. To relieve the energy expenditures-the key component in the concept of energy equity–of low-income communities, governments worldwide have imposed caps on soaring energy prices. However, the inherent mechanisms within the operational schedule remain undiscussed. This paper innovatively provides guidelines for operators to embed energy burden policies into the bulk power system model, by answering two critical questions. ①What is the impact on system price pattern when embedding the locational price constraints? ② How to reformulate the tie-line schedule to meet the equity thresholds? Consequently, a novel bi-level energy equity-constrained tie-line scheduling model is proposed. The conventional economic dispatch is solved at the upper level, and then a preliminary operational schedule is given to the lower level, where we propose an energy equity slackness component variable to evaluate the gap between preliminary and desired equity-satisfied operational schedules. The implicit constraints on the price are converted into explicit feasibility cuts with dual theory. Case studies on test systems demonstrate the reduced energy expenditure for underserved communities, and the optimal tie-line schedule is also validated.
Set of generators
Set of transmission lines
, Set of wind farms and loads
, Feasibility sets for upper-level and lower-level models
a, c, B, C, G, Coefficient matrices of proposed model
J, H, L, K, M
b, d, g, h, f Right-term parameters of proposed model
ctie,t Price of tie-line energy at time t
cg Generation cost of generator g
e
Fl Transmission limit of transmission lines
GSF Generation shift factor
P, P Upper and lower bounds of tie-line power flow
P, P Upper and lower output limits of generator g
Pdt Load of bus d at time t
ugt Status of generator g at time t
wmt Output of wind farm m at time t
ρ, ρ Dual variables of unit output constraints
λt Dual variable of system balance constraints
μ, μ Dual variables of power flow constraints
, , , , , , Dual variables of proposed model in compact
, , notation
D Load vector
esnt Energy equity slackness component variable for bus n at time t
L Lagrangian function of economic dispatch (ED) problem
Mbig Sufficient big constant
Ptie,t Energy flow on tie-line at time t
Pgt Power output of generator g at time t
P, y Variables of proposed model in compact notation
s Vector of energy equity slackness variable
, Binary auxiliary variables under Karush-Kuhn-
, Tucker (KKT) conditions
, Results of and from upper level
, Auxiliary binary variable vectors
DURING the transition to lower-carbon energy sources, it is required that the benefits in the energy system through the intentional design of systems, technologies, procedures, and policies are distributed in fairness and justice [
Public participation and intervenor compensation are critical energy equity tools. Appropriate metrics are also needed to track and evaluate the results of policies, regulations, and programs intended to deliver equitable outcomes [
The above governmental programs made remarkable efforts in providing affordable and accessible cleaner energy equitably. While few of them have created an environment for the operators to consider the energy equity issues within the utility models [
For the aforementioned programs, the internal mechanisms of corresponding market models are significant to developing energy equity-based technologies, procedures, and policies. Although the implications of traditional market models are modified by the novel mechanisms, we regard this as a “market mechanism extension” rather than “market distortion”. The developed model remains optimal within the proposed environment for novel market mechanisms. Entities conventionally participate in day-ahead [
Further, in interconnected systems, the tie-line schedule significantly impacts the prices of each system, and consequently, impacts the consumer payment and energy burden of each community in the entire interconnected system. Therefore, interchange trading in interconnected systems [
According to the aforementioned introduction, the operators from the areas with energy equity issues (e.g., higher energy burdens) are expecting the designs and implementations of specific equity-concerned policies. However, in multi-area systems, the price information is determined by operational details which are preserved by local ISOs [
To fill the research gaps discussed above, a novel tie-line scheduling model is proposed that provides guidelines to market operators for the scheduling strategy and subsidy policy needed when enforcing the energy equity policies. At the upper level of the proposed model, the conventional economic dispatch (ED) problem is solved, and then the preliminary operational schedule is given to the lower-level model. At the lower level, an energy equity slackness component (EESC) variable is proposed, which can evaluate the typical characteristics of the gap between the given operational schedule and the desired schedule that meets the energy equity constraints. Subsequently, the duality theorem is adopted to solve the lower-level model, wherein the implicit social-driven locational price constraints are converted into explicit feasibility cuts, which are sent back to the upper level to iteratively prune the infeasible region of the model. To further integrate the features of the subsidy policy into the energy equity-constrained market, the feasibility cuts are modified as improved optimality cuts, and thereby the model convergence is accelerated. The proposed bi-level tie-line scheduling model provides guidelines to the market operators for how to reformulate operational schedules to achieve the desired system energy price pattern, as well as how to achieve the expected subsidy policy when operational flexibilities are exhausted.
The main contributions of this paper are summarized as follows.
1) A novel bi-level energy equity-constrained tie-line scheduling model for interconnected systems is proposed to embed the energy burden constraints. The model innovatively reveals the inherent mechanism for reformulating tie-line schedules to achieve the desired energy price pattern following the requirements of energy equity policies.
2) In the proposed model, an EESC variable is proposed to relax the lower-level model and also to evaluate the typical characteristics of the gap between the preliminary and the desired energy equity-satisfied operational schedules.
3) The duality theorem is adopted to convert the implicit social-driven cost constraints into explicit feasibility cuts, which are further modified as improved optimality cuts when considering the features of subsidy policy, and consequently accelerate the convergence of the model.
The rest of this paper is organized as follows. Section II presents the energy equity-constrained ED problem, and validates the implicit traits of the energy equity constraints. Section III introduces the proposed bi-level energy equity-constrained tie-line scheduling model. Section IV discusses the solution methodology. Section V gives the computational results. And Section VI presents the concluding remarks.
In this paper, we aim to implement the energy expenditure threshold for low-income communities, acting as price cap constraints into the conventional ED problem. The diagram of a two-area interconnected system is adopted. As shown in

Fig. 1 Diagram of a two-area interconnected system.
In the two-area interconnected system, the sending-end (denoted as S-end hereafter) sends the tie-line price signal to the R-end, and the R-end puts the price into the ED problem, and then returns the purchase plan to the S-end. The ED problem of R-end with energy expenditure constraints (price caps) is presented as follows.
(1) |
s.t.
(2) |
(3) |
(4) |
(5) |
(6) |
In the objective function (1), the first term is the tie-line energy importing cost, and the second term is the generation cost. Constraint (2) gives the upper and lower output limits of generators. In this paper, we assume that the commitment decision of the generators is given priority, then the status ugt denotes the parameters in this model. But note that the proposed model is scalable to solve the unit commitment (UC) problem. Constraint (3) gives the transmission limits of the tie-line. In the proposed model, we assume that there is only one tie-line connecting the two areas, but it is easy to expand to multiple tie-lines.
According to the illustration in Section II, the LMPs are determined by the conventional ED problem. Therefore, the requirements for Ptie should be explored to ensure the model feasibility after embedding the energy cost threshold constraints.
A novel bi-level energy equity-constrained tie-line scheduling model is proposed in this subsection. The desired price pattern is approached by iteratively reformulating the tie-line schedule in a bi-level structure, i.e., the novel ED problem enforces the social-driven energy cost constraints in a hierarchical way. The model is reformulated in (1)-(6), with the objective in (1) and constraints in (2)-(5) and (7)-(16).
(7) |
(8) |
(9) |
(10) |
(11) |
(12) |
(13) |
(14) |
(15) |
(16) |
Based on the preceding discussion, the market operator at the R-end strategically submits the purchase plan of tie-line energy to the S-end, to regulate the local price pattern. Therefore, in (7), the tie-line energy Ptie,t should belong to a feasibility set , which is depicted by (8)-(16). This set itself, also has objective function and constraints that are modeled with given . In (9), we propose an EESC variable esnt to evaluate the gap between the existing operational schedule and the target operational schedule, which is subject to the mandatory energy cost threshold e
In conclusion, the proposed model consists of two layers. At the upper level, the model (1)-(5) solves the classical ED problem; and at the lower level, the model (7)-(15) first proposes an EESC variable to create a relaxed structure, and consequently, the typical characteristics of the gap between the existing operational schedule to the energy equity-constrained operational schedule are evaluated. Based on this bi-level model, we provide guidelines for formulating the operational schedule when the market operator is required to comply with the energy equity policy. This EESC-based relaxed model is essentially a distributed solution to the tie-line scheduling at the R-end, and of course, the S-end also needs to perform a regular ED each time, iteratively in accordance with the R-end.
After introducing the details of the proposed model, the corresponding compact model in vector form is given in this subsection for the convenience of discussing the solution methodology. It is important to note that we have ignored time stamps in the vector model because all the constraints are satisfied in every time slot, except the energy equity constraint (24), which is the constraint to the summation of daily energy cost.
(17) |
s.t.
(18) |
(19) |
(20) |
(21) |
(22) |
(23) |
(24) |
(25) |
(26) |
(27) |
(28) |
(29) |
(30) |
In the objective function (17), y is the vector of the tie-line energy variables. Constraint (18) is related to (2), wherein d is the right-side term after the rearrangement. Constraint (19) comes from the tie-line energy capacity limits given by (3). Constraint (20) is the energy balance constraint extracted from (4), where 1 is the column vector, and is regulated as , and D is the vector of load with the consideration of renewable energy compensation (equivalent to a negative load). Constraint (21) is related to power flow constraints. Constraints (24) and (25) denote the constraints for the EESC variable derived from (9) and (10), wherein the notation “” is the Hadamard product. Constraint (26) indicates that the LMP variables are determined by . Constraint (27) gives the primal feasibility conditions. Constraints (28) and (29) represent the complementarity slackness conditions. K, M, and b are the coefficients after rearranging constraints (13)-(15). And (30) is derived from the stationarity constraints given in (16).
In order to solve the bi-level model presented by (17)-(30) in Section III, we partition it into a master problem and a sub-problem. The master problem overlaps completely with the aforementioned upper-level model (17)-(22) with the exception that (22) is replaced by the proposed feasibility cuts, which are produced after solving the sub-problem based on the duality theorem. The detailed diagram of the solution algorithm is given in Section IV-C after the solution methodology is introduced.
1) Sub-problem
The sub-problem, denoted as S in this part, inherits the structure of the lower-level model (23)-(30), with the following modifications: ① the vector y is regarded as a right-side term to indicate the given purchased tie-line energy capacity; ② constraint (23) is relaxed to the objective function (31) by neglecting the “equals-to-0” requirement, but this feasibility will be ensured by the proposed feasibility cuts afterward; ③ the feasible set Θ is constructed to depict the feasible region determined by LMP variables, in which the constraints can be supplemented directly to the outer sub-problem. Hence, the sub-problem is first formulated as problem S in (31) and (32).
(31) |
s.t.
(32) |
Sub-problem S is formulated as a mixed-integer linear programming (MILP) problem, and algorithms such as Benders decomposition [
(33) |
s.t.
(34) |
The preceding introduction to the lower level of the proposed model demonstrates its responsibility for evaluating the typical characteristics of the energy burden violation based on the given operational schedule. In the solution methodology, this violation is illustrated by the EESC variable s and is thereby regulated to be 0. Consequently, we obtain the dual problem of S′, denoted as R in (35) and (36), and the duality theorem is adopted to evaluate the desired adjustments to the operational schedule because of the energy burden violation.
(35) |
s.t.
(36) |
As problem S′ is an LP, the solved objective value of primal problem S′ equals that of the dual problem R under strong duality. In simpler terms, when the sub-problem is infeasible (), it is equivalent to the objective value of a dual problem (35), i.e., larger than 0. If we denote as the optimal solution of problem R in the
(37) |
2) Master Problem
With the supplement of the feasibility cuts, the master problem in the
(38) |
It is worth noting that (38) is a set of explicit constraints of vector y, i.e., the proposed feasibility cuts convert the implicit energy equity constraints into the explicit supplementary constraints of the tie-line energy purchase plan. By leveraging the proposed EESC variable, the social-driven locational price constraints are relaxed, and the typical violation characteristics in the sub-problem are obtained based on the duality theorem.
Up to this point, we have introduced the tie-line scheduling solution when the requirements from energy equity policies are given to the market operators. However, the operational schedule may vary when given different energy cost thresholds, and the model may even be infeasible if the energy burden threshold is too tight. Hence, in this subsection, we further formulate the subsidy policy guidelines for the proposed tie-line scheduling model by necessary modifications. For the constraint (9) in the sub-problem, if we expand the sum within the parentheses, the second term will be the production of the EBSC variable and the nodal load capacity. As the EBSC variable is supposed to be the slack LMP for the energy burden-suffering node, this production happens to equal the potential subsidies that the market operator must provide to the users, when the given operational schedule is not able to meet the energy equity requirement. Therefore, the original objective function of sub-problem (31) is consistent with minimizing the subsidy
(39) |
According to the conclusions in [
(40) |
is the current solution of the master problem, and the consequent objective solution of the sub-problem given yk is denoted as sk. If , then in each iteration, we repeatedly add (40) into the master problem to cut off the feasible region that corresponds to the solution .
In conclusion, the algorithm for solving the proposed model with subsidy policy is shown in
Algorithm 1 : duality theorem-based algorithm with improved feasibility cuts | |
---|---|
1 |
Set the iteration index , energy burden constraint threshold e |
2 |
Set the upper bound of the proposed model as , and lower bound as |
3 |
Repeat |
4 |
Solve the sub-problem S (31) with the constraints (32), and obtain the optimal solution sk. Update |
5 |
By fixing the outcoming results of binary variables zρ and zµ, the problem S is transformed into LP problem S′ in (33) and (34) |
6 |
Based on strong duality, convert the LP problem S′ to its dual form R in (35) and (36), solve the problem R, and obtain the solution in the |
7 |
Solve the master problem in (39), subjected to constraints (18)-(21), and add the additional improved feasibility cut (40) |
8 |
Obtain the solution, denoted as , and update |
9 |
|
10 |
Until , then submit the tie-line energy purchase plan y to the S-end |
The bi-level structure of the proposed model is also illustrated in

Fig. 2 Schematic diagram of bi-level structure of proposed model.
Due to space limitations and for clarity, some details of the model and solution methodology have not been illustrated, and we acknowledge these details in this subsection.
1) In the modified objective function (39), it is noteworthy that the subsidy term has the same unit with operational cost as “$”, so there is no need to assign a weight coefficient for and thus no optimality gap will be introduced in the proposed model.
2) After solving the proposed model with the solution methodology, the market operator of the R-end submits the current energy purchase plan to the S-end. Then, the S-end will update the offering price based on its own supply curve, and the R-end will develop the tie-line schedule iteratively until the multi-area market is cleared. In the proposed model, we adopt the classical alternating direction method of multipliers (ADMM) [
3) For the cost function of generators in (1), we adopt the simplified form of the linear function. Nevertheless, when concentrating on the distributed clearing market, to enhance the convergence of the regional market clearing process, quadratic economic function (with piece-wise-linear technology employed) is introduced in some models to ensure that the supply curves of both market participants are sloping. There are also many other equivalent and tighter convex forms for the cost function and the constraints in the UC and ED problems. Please refer to [
4) In the numerical simulation section (Section V), to further facilitate the iteration efficiency, we also make modifications to the market information submitted by both participants in (41), wherein subscript i is the iteration index between S-end and R-end when clearing the distributed market (be sure to distinguish from the tie-line scheduling iteration within the R-end). Correction coefficients and vary from to modify
(41) |
5) Considering that we are focusing on the constraints for locational price in the systems, it should be noted that the negative nodal price may occur in some extreme circumstances, especially when renewable energy generators participate in bidding. However, in the proposed model, we focus on the total energy cost of certain buses, and the negative prices are unlikely to occur at load buses.
6) The uncertainties of renewable energy resources are not specifically considered in this paper because we want to salient the inter-area trading mechanism with energy equity constraints. However, it is easy to enforce them with robust or stochastic methods, which are also parts of our future works.
In the simulation, we first apply the proposed model and solution methodology to the smaller test systems consisting of two and three Pennsylvania-New Jersey-Maryland (PJM) 5-bus systems, then adopt the larger Northeast Power Coordinating Council (NPCC) test system to validate the effectiveness of the proposed tie-line scheduling model with energy equity constraints.
The test system in this subsection, as shown in

Fig. 3 Diagram of two PJM 5-bus test systems.
The operational horizon is set to be 24 hours with a one-hour resolution. After applying the proposed model and the solution methodology, the operational results under different required energy cost thresholds (e
e | S-end cost ($) | R-end cost ($) | Total cost ($) | Social cost ($) | S-end generation (MWh) | R-end generation (MWh) | Exchange (MWh) | ||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Operation | Tie-line import | Subsidy | |||||||
45000 | 65665 | 66412 | 45875 | 0 | 177952 | 10365 | 6059 | 2853 | |
43000 | 64393 | 59932 | 53907 | 0 | 178232 | 280 | 10782 | 5654 | 3258 |
41000 | 62219 | 52133 | 64761 | 0 | 179113 | 1161 | 11307 | 5119 | 3792 |
39000 | 61092 | 48284 | 70468 | 706 | 180550 | 2598 | 11606 | 4809 | 4103 |
37000 | 61092 | 48284 | 70468 | 2707 | 182551 | 4599 | 11606 | 4809 | 4103 |
With more intensified e
For a more specific illustration, the cleared tie-line energy purchase plan and cleared price are shown in
e | Tie-line energy (MW) | Cleared price ($/MW) | LMP of bus | S-end expense (1 | R-end expense (1 | Total energy expenditure (1 |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
45000 | 149.48 | 11.14 | 11.14 | 134.0 | 149.2 | 283.2 |
43000 | 151.28 | 11.76 | 11.11 | 137.1 | 143.3 | 280.4 |
41000 | 186.47 | 12.09 | 10.50 | 141.4 | 136.3 | 277.7 |
39000 | 215.38 | 12.39 | 9.99 | 143.2 | 132.3 | 275.5 |
37000 | 215.38 | 12.39 | 9.99 | 143.2 | 132.3 | 275.5 |
The iteration between the areas is explained by the updated supply curves of the R-end, as shown in

Fig. 4 Updated supply curves of R-end. (a) Curves in each iteration. (b) Detailed curves when e
To verify the sustainability of the proposed model, we further compare the conventional coupon-based models and the proposed model, and the economic results are given in
e | Total cost ($) | Social cost ($) | Coupon cost ($) |
---|---|---|---|
45000 | 177952 | ||
43000 | 178232 | 280 | 2000 |
41000 | 179113 | 1161 | 4000 |
39000 | 180550 | 2598 | 6000 |
37000 | 182551 | 4599 | 8000 |
The support from the S-end is illustrated in

Fig. 5 Output of generators at S-end with different e
In this subsection, we apply the proposed model to a three PJM 5-bus interconnected test system to verify its scalability. The schematic diagram of the supplementary case study is shown in

Fig. 6 Diagram of three PJM 5-bus interconnected test system.
e | S-end cost ($) | R-end #1 cost ($) | R-end #2 cost ($) | Total cost ($) | |||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Operation | Tie-line import | Subsidy | Operation | Tie-line import | |||
45000 | 67608 | 66884 | 45479 | 0 | 72572 | 12691 | 265234 |
43000 | 66336 | 60404 | 53511 | 0 | 72969 | 12884 | 266104 |
41000 | 64162 | 52605 | 64365 | 0 | 73681 | 12913 | 267726 |
39000 | 63035 | 48756 | 70072 | 791 | 74773 | 13206 | 270633 |
37000 | 63035 | 48756 | 70072 | 2792 | 74773 | 13206 | 272634 |
It is illustrated in
Following the application of the proposed model to the smaller test system, in this subsection, we apply the proposed model to a larger system, consisting of two NPCC 140-bus test systems, to validate the scalability of the model. The detailed network data is drawn from [
In this test system, the low-income bus is Bus 114, and the energy price is higher due to congestion in transmission line 116 (buses 90-114). After implementing different energy cost thresholds on the proposed tie-line scheduling model, the market clearing results are shown in
e | S-end cost (1 | R-end cost (1 | Total cost (1 | Social cost (1 | S-end generation (GWh) | R-end generation (GWh) | Exchange (GWh) | ||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Operation | Tie-line import | Subsidy | |||||||
1.00 | 4.799 | 4.472 | 2.866 | 0 | 12.137 | 314.17 | 297.46 | 24.45 | |
0.97 | 4.726 | 4.466 | 2.945 | 0 | 12.138 | 0.001 | 314.68 | 296.95 | 24.96 |
0.94 | 4.671 | 4.461 | 3.011 | 0 | 12.143 | 0.006 | 315.30 | 396.33 | 25.58 |
0.91 | 4.597 | 4.456 | 3.101 | 0 | 12.154 | 0.017 | 315.89 | 295.74 | 26.17 |
0.88 | 4.541 | 4.439 | 3.189 | 0.017 | 12.186 | 0.049 | 316.58 | 295.05 | 26.86 |
The results in

Fig. 7 Energy price patterns with and without social-driven cost constraints. (a) With social-driven cost constraints. (b) Without social-driven cost constraints.
In this paper, we propose a novel bi-level energy equity-constrained tie-line scheduling model for interconnected systems to characterize the concept of energy equity, and develop technical implementation schemes for potential energy burden policies. The proposed model evaluates the gap between the given operational schedule and the desired equity-constrained schedule. The proposed model also provides guidelines to market operators for how to develop tie-line schedules as price takers to achieve the desired energy price pattern. Further, a subsidy policy is adopted in the proposed model by leveraging the improved optimality cuts, along with the duality theorem. In the case studies, the effectiveness of the proposed model is validated by the impact of the energy equity implementation, and the cost of meeting the requirements of energy equity is verified to be higher. In the future, we plan to further study energy equity by considering energy storage device planning problems under renewable energy uncertainty.
References
S. Carley and D. M. Konisky, “The justice and equity implications of the clean energy transition,” Nature Energy, vol. 5, no. 8, p. 8, Aug. 2020. [Baidu Scholar]
K. E. Jenkins, B. K. Sovacool, N. Mouter et al., “The methodologies, geographies, and technologies of energy justice: a systematic and comprehensive review,” Environmental Research Letters, vol. 16, no. 4, p. 043009, Apr. 2021. [Baidu Scholar]
U.S. Department of Energy. (2024, May). Low-income community energy solutions. [Online]. Available: https://www.energy.gov/scep/slsc/low-income-community-energy-solutions [Baidu Scholar]
O. Ma, K. Laymon, M. H. Day et al., “Low-income energy affordability data (LEAD) tool methodology,” Tech. Rep., No. NREL/TP-6A20-74249, National Renewable Energy Laboratory, Golden, USA, Jul. 2019. [Baidu Scholar]
K. Jenkins, D. McCauley, R. Heffron et al., “Energy justice: a conceptual review,” Energy Research & Social Science, vol. 11, pp. 174-182, Jan. 2016. [Baidu Scholar]
C. Farley, J. Howat, J. Bosco et al. (2021, Nov.). Advancing equity in utility regulation. [Online]. Availbale: https://escholarship.org/content/qt1mr715sx/qt1mr715sx.pdf [Baidu Scholar]
R. Day, G. Walker, and N. Simcock, “Conceptualising energy use and energy poverty using a capabilities framework,” Energy Policy, vol. 93, pp. 255-264, Jun. 2016. [Baidu Scholar]
U.S. Department of Energy. (2024, May). Weatherization Assistance Program (WAP). [Online]. Available: https://www.energy.gov/scep/wap/about-weatherization-assistance-program [Baidu Scholar]
U.S. Department of Health and Human Services. (2024, May). Low Income Home Energy Assistance Program (LIHEAP). [Online]. Available: https://www.acf.hhs.gov/ocs /programs/liheap [Baidu Scholar]
BBC News. (2023, Aug). French government limits electricity price rises. [Online]. Available: https://www.bbc.com/news/business-60112068. [Baidu Scholar]
The Local. (2022, Jan.). Denmark could give tax-free sum to families with high heating bills. [Online]. Available: https://www.thelocal.dk/20220127/ denmark-could-give-tax-free-sum-to-families-with-high-heating-bills [Baidu Scholar]
UK Government. (2023, May). Energy price guarantee. [Online]. Available: https://www.gov.uk/government/publications/energy-bills-support/ energy-bills-support-factsheet-8-september-2022 [Baidu Scholar]
T. Levin, J. Bistline, R. Sioshansi et al., “Energy storage solutions to decarbonize electricity through enhanced capacity expansion modelling,” Nature Energy, vol. 8, no. 11, pp. 1199-1208, Sept. 2023. [Baidu Scholar]
M. Brown, A. Soni, M. Lapsa et al., “Low-income energy affordability: conclusions from a literature review,” Tech. Rep., No. ORNL/TM-2019/1150, Oak Ridge National Laboratory, Oak Ridge, USA, Mar. 2020. [Baidu Scholar]
C. Li, F. Li, S. Jiang et al., “Siting and sizing of DG units considering energy equity: model, solution, and guidelines,” IEEE Transactions on Smart Grid, vol. 15, no. 4, pp. 3681-3693, Jul. 2024. [Baidu Scholar]
A. Merzic, M. Music, and Z. Haznadar, “Conceptualizing sustainable development of conventional power systems in developing countries–a contribution towards low carbon future,” Energy, vol. 126, pp. 112-123, May 2017. [Baidu Scholar]
B. Tarekegne, D. Powell, K. Oikonomou et al., “Analysis of energy justice and equity impacts from replacing peaker plants with energy storage,” in Proceedings of 2022 IEEE Electrical Energy Storage Application and Technologies Conference (EESAT), Austin, USA, Nov. 2022, pp. 1-5. [Baidu Scholar]
Oregon State. (2021, Dec.). HB 3141. [Online]. Available: https://olis.oregonlegislature.gov/liz/2021R1/Measures/Overview/HB3141 [Baidu Scholar]
S. Michener, R. O’Neil, S. Atcitty et al., “Energy storage for social equity roundtable report,” Tech. Rep., No. PNNL-31964, Pacific Northwest National Laboratory, Tri-cities, USA, Sept. 2021. [Baidu Scholar]
D. J. Bednar and T. G. Reames, “Recognition of and response to energy poverty in the United States,” Nature Energy, vol. 5, no. 6, pp. 432-439, Mar. 2020. [Baidu Scholar]
W. Gu and R. Sioshansi, “Market equilibria with energy storage as flexibility resources,” IEEE Open Access Journal of Power and Energy, vol. 9, pp. 584-597, Nov. 2022. [Baidu Scholar]
X. Fang and M. Cui, “Analytical model of day-ahead and real-time price correlation in strategic wind power offering,” Journal of Modern Power Systems and Clean Energy, vol. 8, no. 5, pp. 1024-1027, Sept. 2020. [Baidu Scholar]
Y. Du, F. Li, H. Zandi et al., “Approximating Nash equilibrium in day-ahead electricity market bidding with multi-agent deep reinforcement learning,” Journal of Modern Power Systems and Clean Energy, vol. 9, no. 3, pp. 534-544, May 2021. [Baidu Scholar]
S. Liu, Y. Jiang, Z. Lin et al., “Data-driven two-step day-ahead electricity price forecasting considering price spikes,” Journal of Modern Power Systems and Clean Energy, vol. 11, no. 2, pp. 523-533, Mar. 2023. [Baidu Scholar]
X. Fang, B.-M. Hodge, E. Du et al., “Introducing uncertainty components in locational marginal prices for pricing wind power and load uncertainties,” IEEE Transactions on Power Systems, vol. 34, no. 3, pp. 2013-2024, May 2019. [Baidu Scholar]
X. Yang, C. Gu, X. Yan et al., “Reliability-based probabilistic network pricing with demand uncertainty,” IEEE Transactions on Power Systems, vol. 35, no. 5, pp. 3342-3352, Sept. 2020. [Baidu Scholar]
H. Wang, Z. Bie, and H. Ye, “Locational marginal pricing for flexibility and uncertainty with moment information,” IEEE Transactions on Power Systems, vol. 38, no. 3, pp. 2761-2775, May 2023. [Baidu Scholar]
A. Campbell, “Cap prices or cap revenues? The dilemma of electric utility networks,” Energy Economics, vol. 74, pp. 802-812, Aug. 2018. [Baidu Scholar]
C. Le Coq and H. Orzen, “Price caps and fluctuating demands in electricity markets: Experimental evidence of competitive bidding,” in Proceedings of 2012 9th International Conference on the European Energy Market, Florence, Italy, May 2012, pp. 1-4. [Baidu Scholar]
J. Yao, S. S. Oren, and I. Adler, “Two-settlement electricity markets with price caps and Cournot generation firms,” European Journal of Operational Research, vol. 181, no. 3, pp. 1279-1296, Sept. 2007. [Baidu Scholar]
S. Cowan, “Price-cap regulation,” Swedish Economic Policy Review, vol. 9, no.2, pp. 167-188, Jan. 2022. [Baidu Scholar]
Z. Yan and Y. Xu, “A multi-agent deep reinforcement learning method for cooperative load frequency control of a multi-area power system,” IEEE Transactions on Power Systems, vol. 35, no. 6, pp. 4599-4608, Nov. 2020. [Baidu Scholar]
R. Chen, D. Ke, Y. Sun et al., “Hierarchical frequency-dependent chance constrained unit commitment for bulk AC/DC hybrid power systems with wind power generation,” Journal of Modern Power Systems and Clean Energy, vol. 11, no. 4, pp. 1053-1064, Jul. 2023. [Baidu Scholar]
F. Zhao, E. Litvinov, and T. Zheng, “A marginal equivalent decomposition method and its application to multi-area optimal power flow problems,” IEEE Transactions on Power Systems, vol. 29, no. 1, pp. 53-61, Jan. 2014. [Baidu Scholar]
S. Huang, Y. Sun, and Q. Wu, “Stochastic economic dispatch with wind using versatile probability distribution and L-BFGS-B based dual decomposition,” IEEE Transactions on Power Systems, vol. 33, no. 6, pp. 6254-6263, Nov. 2018. [Baidu Scholar]
A. Tosatto, T. Weckesser, and S. Chatzivasileiadis, “Market integration of HVDC lines: internalizing HVDC losses in market clearing,” IEEE Transactions on Power Systems, vol. 35, no. 1, pp. 451-461, Jan. 2020. [Baidu Scholar]
Q. Xu, N. Zhang, C. Kang et al., “A game theoretical pricing mechanism for multi-area spinning reserve trading considering wind power uncertainty,” IEEE Transactions on Power Systems, vol. 31, no. 2, pp. 1084-1095, Mar. 2016. [Baidu Scholar]
J. Wang, H. Zhong, Z. Yang et al., “Incentive mechanism for clearing energy and reserve markets in multi-area power systems,” IEEE Transactions on Sustainable Energy, vol. 11, no. 4, pp. 2470-2482, Oct. 2020. [Baidu Scholar]
J. Ma, F. B. B. Rolim, A. Elkasrawy et al., “A zonal capacity market model with energy storage for transmission and distribution,” IEEE Open Access Journal of Power and Energy, vol. 9, pp. 398-408, Aug. 2022. [Baidu Scholar]
C. Lin, H. Liang, A. Pang et al., “Data-driven surrogate-assisted method for high-dimensional multi-area combined economic/emission dispatch,” Journal of Modern Power Systems and Clean Energy, vol. 12, no. 1, pp. 52-64, Jan. 2024. [Baidu Scholar]
J. Zhu, X. Mo, Y. Xia et al., “Fully-decentralized optimal power flow of multi-area power systems based on parallel dual dynamic programming,” IEEE Transactions on Power Systems, vol. 37, no. 2, pp. 927-941, Mar. 2022. [Baidu Scholar]
L. L. Kiesling, Deregulation, Innovation and Market Liberalization: Electricity Regulation in a Continually Evolving Environment. London: Routledge, 2008. [Baidu Scholar]
R. Rahmaniani, T. G. Crainic, M. Gendreau et al., “The Benders decomposition algorithm: a literature review,” European Journal of Operational Research, vol. 259, no. 3, pp. 801-817, Jun. 2017. [Baidu Scholar]
B. Zeng and L. Zhao, “Solving two-stage robust optimization problems using a column-and-constraint generation method,” Operations Research Letters, vol. 41, no. 5, pp. 457-461, Sept. 2013. [Baidu Scholar]
T. L. Magnanti and R. T. Wong, “Accelerating Benders decomposition: algorithmic enhancement and model selection criteria,” Operations Research, vol. 29, no. 3, pp. 464-484, Jun. 1981. [Baidu Scholar]
N. B. Asl and S. A. MirHassani, “Accelerating Benders decomposition: multiple cuts via multiple solutions,” Journal of Combinatorial Optimization, vol. 37, no. 3, pp. 806-826, Apr. 2019. [Baidu Scholar]
P. Wang, Q. Wu, S. Huang et al., “ADMM-based distributed active and reactive power control for regional AC power grid with wind farms,” Journal of Modern Power Systems and Clean Energy, vol. 10, no. 3, pp. 588-596, May 2022. [Baidu Scholar]
J. Ostrowski, M. F. Anjos, and A. Vannelli, “Tight mixed integer linear programming formulations for the unit commitment problem,” IEEE Transactions on Power Systems, vol. 27, no. 1, pp. 39-46, Feb. 2012. [Baidu Scholar]
G. Morales-España, J. M. Latorre, and A. Ramos, “Tight and compact MILP formulation for the thermal unit commitment problem,” IEEE Transactions on Power Systems, vol. 28, no. 4, pp. 4897-4908, Nov. 2013. [Baidu Scholar]
F. Li and R. Bo, “DCOPF-based LMP simulation: algorithm, comparison with ACOPF, and sensitivity,” IEEE Transactions on Power Systems, vol. 22, no. 4, pp. 1475-1485, Nov. 2007. [Baidu Scholar]
F. Li and Q. Zhang. (2024, May). ENLITEN-Grid-Econ-Data. [Online]. Available: https://github.com/enliten/ENLITEN-Grid-Econ-Data [Baidu Scholar]
N. Parsly, J. Wang, N. West et al., “DiME and AGVis: a distributed messaging environment and geographical visualizer for large-scale power system simulation,” in Proceedings of 2023 North American Power Symposium (NAPS), Asheville, USA, Oct. 2023, pp. 1-5. [Baidu Scholar]
F. Li, K. Tomsovic, and H. Cui, “A large-scale testbed as a virtual power grid: for closed-loop controls in research and testing,” IEEE Power and Energy Magazine, vol. 18, no. 2, pp. 60-68, Mar.-Apr. 2020. [Baidu Scholar]