Abstract
This paper addresses two issues that concern the electricity market participants under the European day-ahead market (DAM) framework, namely the feasibility of the attained schedules and the non-confiscation of cleared volumes. To address the first issue, new resource-specific orders, i.e., thermal orders for thermal generating units, demand response orders for load responsive resources, and energy limited orders for storage resources, are proposed and incorporated in the existing European DAM clearing problem. To address the second issue, two approaches which lead to a non-confiscatory market are analyzed① discriminatory pricing with side-payments (U.S. paradigm); and ② non-discriminatory pricing excluding out-of-money orders (European paradigm). A comparison is performed between the two approaches to investigate the most appropriate pricing rule in terms of social welfare, derived revenues for the sellers, and efficiency of the attained results. The proposed model with new resource-specific products is evaluated in a European test system, achieving robust solutions. The feasibility of the attained schedules is demonstrated when using resource-specific orders compared with block orders. Finally, the results indicate the supremacy of discriminatory pricing with side-payments compared with the current European pricing rule.
AS a main pillar towards the development of a single European electricity market [
Even though block and complex orders embed some of the techno-economic characteristics of thermal generating units, they are not able to capture detailed operating constraints. This issue has been raised by stakeholders in Europe, and the ideas of the incorporation of thermal orders (THOs) have emerged [
THOs could also contribute to a more efficient integration of renewable energy sources (RESs), due to their flexibility to adapt more accurately to changing net load (load minus RES) conditions compared with block orders.
At the same time, a gradual transformation is attempted from a conventional-resource market to the one with widespread diffusion of renewable generation [
In terms of clearing, the European DAM constitutes a non-convex problem since binary variables are used for the modeling of indivisible market orders. Pricing rules in such non-convex auctions have been put under scrutiny by the scientific community [
1) Discriminatory pricing with side-payments (Case A): a uniform price is obtained from market clearing and the additional side-payments (uplifts) are provided for fixed costs that could not be recovered through uniform prices. This pricing rule is generally followed by the U.S. power markets, e.g., CAISO [
2) Non-discriminatory pricing internalizing fixed costs (Case B): the price formation considers the problem non-convexities in an attempt to reflect the participants’ fixed costs as well. References [
3) Non-discriminatory pricing excluding out-of-money orders (Case C): a uniform price is derived from market clearing, which is the final settlement price. However, the appropriate controls are included in the algorithm to ensure that no market order is cleared which incurs a loss to the participant. The concept of removing paradoxically accepted orders (PAOs) from the final market solution has applications in most European DAMs [
Finally, for example, compared with the U.S. system, one idea of the European model is the simplicity of the bidding formats, e.g., block orders. Our position is that this is a matter of participant choice and not a matter that should be pre-defined from a market-design point of view. Put it differently, both choices could be provided to the participants (e.g., block orders and resource-specific orders), so that they can decide which is the best option for them in everyday operation. With regards to the algorithm complexity, the mathematical problem formulation under the inclusion of resource-specific orders is tractable in the case study examined in this paper. Notably, the execution time is lower in Case A than that in Case C, which involves an iterative process.
Several research works have been proposed to appropriately model the block and complex orders under the European framework, in order to deal with non-convexities and to appropriately handle the PAOs.
Reference | Model | Block order | Linked block order | Exclusive group of block orders | PUN order | MIC order | THO, DRO, ELO | Number of zones | Case (pricing rule) |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
[ | LP | No | No | No | No | No | No | B | |
[ | MILP | Yes | No | No | No | No | No | B | |
[ | MILP | Yes | No | No | No | No | No | B | |
[ | MCP | No | No | No | Yes | No | No | 5 | C |
[ | MILP | Yes | No | No | No | No | No | C | |
[ | MILP | No | No | No | No | No | No | 24 | B |
[ | MILP | No | No | No | No | No | No | A, B | |
[ | MPEC | Yes | Yes | No | No | No | No | 10 | C |
[ | MILP | Yes | Yes | Yes | No | Yes | No | 42 | C |
[ | LP,MCP | Yes | No | No | No | No | No | 42 | C |
[ | MILP | Yes | Yes | Yes | No | Yes | No | 42 | C |
[ | MILP | Yes | No | No | No | No | No | C | |
[ | LP | No | No | No | No | No | No | 1 | A |
[ | MILP | No | No | No | No | Yes | No | 300 | C |
[ | MILP, MCP | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | No | 42 | C |
[ | MILP | Yes | No | No | Yes | Yes | No | 3 | C |
[ | MILP | Yes | No | No | Yes | No | No | 6 | |
[ | MILP | Yes | No | No | Yes | No | No | 6 | C |
[ | MILP | Yes | No | No | Yes | No | No | 22 | C |
[ | MIQCP | Yes | Yes | No | Yes | Yes | No | 53 | C |
[ | MILP, MCP | Yes | No | No | Yes | Yes | No | 14 | C |
[ | MILP | Yes | Yes | No | No | Yes | No | 1 | C |
[ | MILP | Yes | Yes | Yes | No | Yes | No | 1 | C |
[ | MILP | Yes | No | No | No | Yes | No | ||
This paper | MILP | Yes | Yes | Yes | No | Yes | Yes | 42 | A, C |
Note: DRO and ELO are short for demand response order and energy limited order, respectively; and in this table only, MCP refers to the mixed complementarity problem.
In [
Reference [
A revenue-constrained market clearing method is studied in [
In [
A mathematical formulation that incorporates various market products and transmission constraints of the European DAM is proposed in [
In [
Reference [
Finally, the combination of the minimum income, load gradient, and auxiliary scheduled stop complex conditions is examined in [
The contributions of this paper are as follows.
1) Inclusion of “resource-specific” orders in the European DAM clearing problem, by extending a previous market clearing formulation [
2) Analysis and comparison of different pricing rules that ensure economic non-confiscation of all order types. For Case A, discriminatory pricing with ex-post side-payments is considered, while for Case C, a modeling framework is constructed where all orders are subject to revenue-constrained controls during an iterative process. Case B is not investigated in this work.
3) The proposed modeling framework is evaluated using the ENTSO-E zonal system, aiming to assess the computational complexity of the benchmark model in the presence of the new order types.
The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. Section II provides the problem formulation and the solution algorithm. Section III elaborates on the case study and results. The basic conclusions of the conducted research are drawn in Section IV along with ideas for future consideration.
The proposed DAM clearing model is mathematically formulated as an MILP problem.
(1) |
(2) |
(3) |
Inequality (4) expresses the minimum and maximum exchange limits in the interconnections based on the available transfer capacities. Notably, high-voltage direct current (HVDC) lines with high ramping capabilities may lead to big variations of the power flows between two consecutive trading periods. In this case, the inadequate ramp capabilities and available reserves of generators may not be able to cover possible rapid changes in real time. To this end, (5) imposes ramping limitations on the variations of each zone’s net position between successive hours [
(4) |
(5) |
(6) |
Constraints (7)-(11) model the clearing conditions of orders that are currently tradable in the European DAMs. More specifically, (7) denotes the upper clearing limit of simple hourly demand and supply orders. In (8), ramping limitations are enforced in the cleared quantities of successive trading periods for supply orders subject to the load gradient condition (Iberian market). These constraints are not imposed for the first trading period . In (9), the cleared quantity of a block order is delimited between its minimum and maximum acceptance ratios (the latter is equal to 1). Constraint (10) determines the relationship between a linked block order lbo and its “parent” block order bo. The main purpose of linked block orders is to assist producers in scheduling their generating units either at zero production or above their technical minimum production.
(7) |
(8) |
(9) |
(10) |
(11) |
Inequality (11) models the clearing condition of block orders belonging to an exclusive group eg. Between the various block orders submitted by a participant within an exclusive group, the optimization criterion selects the one that maximizes the objective function. Such order type allows participants to propose for different production patterns. The disadvantage is that the algorithm may only choose between the pre-defined blocks by the participant, without being flexible to optimally schedule the output of the generating units at an hourly level depending on system conditions.
The proposed THOs model the successive operating states of a thermal generating unit upon start-up. As shown in

Fig. 1 Operating states of a THO.
Constraints (12)-(16) model the aforementioned operating states. Equations (
(12) |
(13) |
(14) |
(15) |
(16) |
Constraints (17) and (18) represent the minimum up/down time limitation of the THO. The logical relations of the clearing status binary variables are provided in (19)-(23). For example, (19) ensures that a THO is in only one clearing status in a given trading hour. Note that constraints (22) and (23) can be omitted without altering the problem solution; they are proposed for a faster execution. Constraints (24) and (25) describe the upper and lower limits for the cleared quantity of a THO, respectively. Finally, (26) imposes hourly ramping restrictions on the cleared quantities between consecutive trading periods.
(17) |
(18) |
(19) |
(20) |
(21) |
(22) |
(23) |
(24) |
(25) |
(26) |
A dispatchable consumer may not be able to provide its responsiveness unless during a minimum period of time, as provisioned in (27). Similarly, the dispatchable load may not be available during extended periods of time, thus a maximum delivery period is foreseen in (28). Limitations may also exist in the period between two successive activations; therefore, a minimum baseload period is ensured in (29). The participant may limit the frequency of activations in the course of a day, as per (30). Constraints (31)-(33) model the logical relationships of binary variables denoting the clearing status for the DROs. Again, (33) can be omitted without altering the problem solution.
(27) |
(28) |
(29) |
(30) |
(31) |
(32) |
(33) |
Demand response resources usually respond to instructed variations of their load with high ramp capability. Occasionally, however, the full provision of resources may take some time; load pickup rates and load drop rates in (34) resemble the respective ramp rates of the generating units. Finally, the maximum and minimum offered quantities of a DRO are imposed in (35). Note that the synchronization, start-up, and shut-down phases presented earlier for THOs mimic specific power trajectory limitations of thermal turbines. In case such operating phases are considered appropriate also for the DROs, a similar modeling approach could be followed.
(34) |
(35) |
Energy storage resources are able to exploit the market price spreads between the periods of high and low demands. This strategy, referred to as arbitrage, is reflected in the last term of objective function (1) and involves purchasing low-price energy at off-peak hours (i.e., charging the storage resource) and selling it back to the DAM at a reasonably higher price (i.e., discharging the storage resource). The ELOs proposed here are intended to address generic storage constraints, facilitating the participation of various storage resources in the DAM (e.g., water reservoir or electrochemical batteries).
Constraints (36) and (37) impose the minimum and maximum discharging and charging capabilities of an ELO, respectively. Constraint (38) ensures that an ELO will not be cleared in charging and discharging statuses simultaneously, which is rational from a market design point of view. Note that this constraint can be omitted, since under normal trading behavior, the optimization criterion will ensure this condition.
(36) |
(37) |
(38) |
(39) |
(40) |
(41) |
(42) |
(43) |
The DAM clearing model described above incorporates integer (binary) variables to model the various types of orders. As a result, an MILP problem is formulated and the attained dual variables do not determine the MCPs in a straightforward manner. The method used in this paper for the computation of MCPs is based on [
(46) |
As shown in

Fig. 2 Iterative algorithm.
1) Step 1: the DAM problem in (1)-(45) is solved first to attain the cleared volumes of all submitted orders. The optimization horizon is 24 hours.
2) Step 2: the MCPs of each bidding zone are calculated using (46).
3) Step 3: consecutive controls identify any: ① PAOs; ② supply orders, THOs, DROs, and ELOs that do not fulfill their MIC. PAOs are immediately excluded from the order book. For supply orders, THOs, DROs, and ELOs that do not fulfill their MIC in current iteration, the specific controls are applied as described below.
4) Step 4: in case where there are no PAOs and orders that do not meet their MIC, the algorithm terminates. Otherwise, the process continues with Step 1.
The respective algorithm for Case A includes only Steps 1 and 2. No order control is applied and the process terminates with a single iteration. Side-payments are then calculated ex-post.
In Step 3 of each iteration, the welfare of each block order is calculated as:
(47) |
where is the optimal value of derived from Step 1 of current iteration. In case the welfare is negative, the order is designated as PAO and is removed from the order book.
The attained market revenue of each supply order submitted with an MIC condition is calculated as:
(48) |
is compared with the revenue required by the participant . The latter incorporates both the variable term and the fixed term of an MIC order:
(49) |
If , the order is removed from the order book. However, if the supply order is close to fulfil its MIC in a given iteration, Y opportunities are provided to the order for being accepted in the following iterations. Specifically, the “revenue ratio” is calculated in current iteration as:
(50) |
If this ratio is lower than a specific threshold X (e.g., 10%), another opportunities are provided to this order for meeting its MIC. Similar MIC controls are implemented for the newly proposed orders, based on the comparison between attained market revenues (51)-(52) and required revenues (53)-(55).
(51) |
(52) |
(53) |
(54) |
(55) |
The derivation of market dearing process is given in Appendix A.
The proposed model is applied in a test system comprising 42 European bidding zones (indicated by the abbreviations) and 72 interconnectors, as shown in

Fig. 3 European bidding zones and interconnectors.
For back-testing purposes, we first evaluate the performance of the benchmark model (i.e., without the proposed resource-specific orders) in a real-world market case. Specifically, the Greek DAM has been simulated for the 31 days of December 2021, by utilizing the real hybrid curves and block orders as published by the Hellenic Energy Exchange [

Fig. 4 Curves of actual and simulated DAM clearing prices.
For comparison purposes, three test cases are examined below.
1) Case A. One-shot process includes only Steps 1 and 2 of the algorithm, without any order control. To render the market non-confiscatory, additional make-whole payments are assumed.
2) Case C. The block orders, THOs, DROs, and ELOs which incur a negative welfare to their participants are removed from the order book, according to the description of Section II-C, to ensure non-confiscation.
3) Case BO. Similar with Case C with the exception that the THOs are substituted by comparable block and linked block orders. When a THO has a minimum up time longer than 24 hours, a respective 24-hour block order is created in Case BO with a quantity equal to the minimum quantity of the THO and a price equal to the average price of the THO over the 24 hours. On top of this block order, 24 hourly linked block orders are created at the same hourly price as the THO. When a THO has a minimum up time shorter than 24 hours, a respective exclusive group of orders is created in the Case BO. Each block of the exclusive group starts at each successive hour of the day and has a duration equal to the minimum up time of the respective THO.
Typical examples of THO clearing are presented in

Fig. 5 Typical examples of THO clearing. (a) THO1. (b) THO2.
In
Note that the THOs could be an additional possibility to the block orders, or they could entirely replace the block orders in the European market clearing algorithm. Consider the following example: a participant submits a block order with MWh/h for 7 hours. The minimum acceptance ratio is . This means that the block order can be accepted for any quantity between 60 MWh/h and 100 MWh/h. The accepted quantity will be the same for all hours, since is the same and the acceptance ratio is common for all hours. Alternatively, the participant may submit a THO with the maximum quantity MWh and the minimum quantity MWh for the same 7 hours. The minimum up time of this order is hours; thus, this order will be either accepted for the full 7 hours or rejected in its entirety (similar to the block order). Additionally, the synchronization, start-up, and shut-down time of this order may be set to be zero and the start-up profile can be left empty. This means that the order will not follow the different operating trajectories of thermal unit (similar to the block order). The only difference between the block order and the THO in this case is that the accepted quantity for any given hour may be different for the THO while it will be the same for the block order. This means that the THO provides a wider solution space to the algorithm, which can lead to its acceptance in cases where an equivalent block order would have been rejected. Finally, a common acceptance ratio could be introduced for the THO as well, with the possibility to be activated by the user or not. In this case, all block order features are simulated by the THO, and thus the THOs could fully replace the block orders to minimize complexity.
Additionally, the indivisible character of the block orders produces more frequent jumps in the MCPs from hour to hour, as shown in

Fig. 6 MCPs in Greek bidding zone.
Another THO is presented in

Fig. 7 Typical example of DRO clearing.

Fig. 8 Typical example of ELO clearing.
Both Cases A and C ensure economic non-confiscation for the sellers since they compensate for the entirety of the sellers’ costs. In Case A, side-payments are calculated ex-post as the difference between the required revenues of participants and the attained revenues in the first iteration of the algorithm. In this paragraph, a comparison is performed between Cases A and C in terms of social welfare, derived revenues of the sellers, and robustness of the attained results.
Iteration | Social welfare (M€) | PAOs removed | Number of eligible order () | Number of removed order () | Execution time (s) | ||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Supply order | THO | DRO | ELO | Supply order | THO | DRO | ELO | ||||
1 | 5792.997 | 6 | 1 | 3 | 7 | 39 | 5 | 2 | 12 | 35 | 34.03 |
2 | 5792.902 | 1 | 1 | 4 | 7 | 39 | 2 | 0 | 0 | 0 | 32.94 |
3 | 5792.899 | 0 | 1 | 4 | 7 | 39 | 2 | 0 | 0 | 0 | 32.89 |
4 | 5792.722 | 3 | 0 | 1 | 0 | 0 | 2 | 0 | 0 | 0 | 31.78 |
5 | 5792.717 | 2 | 0 | 1 | 0 | 0 | 1 | 0 | 0 | 0 | 31.94 |
6 | 5792.715 | 4 | 0 | 1 | 0 | 0 | 0 | 0 | 0 | 0 | 32.01 |
7 | 5792.717 | 1 | 0 | 1 | 0 | 0 | 0 | 0 | 0 | 0 | 31.54 |
8 | 5792.716 | 2 | 0 | 1 | 0 | 0 | 0 | 0 | 0 | 0 | 33.41 |
9 | 5792.717 | 0 | 0 | 0 | 0 | 0 | 0 | 1 | 0 | 0 | 32.50 |
10 | 5792.716 | 0 | 0 | 0 | 0 | 0 | 0 | 0 | 0 | 0 | 31.53 |
Iteration | Market revenue (M€) | Side-payment (M€) | Total revenue (M€) |
---|---|---|---|
1 (Case A) | 376.057 | 0.136 | 376.193 |
2 | 376.459 | 0.013 | 376.472 |
3 | 376.524 | 0.021 | 376.545 |
4 | 376.773 | 0.016 | 376.789 |
5 | 376.941 | 0.008 | 376.949 |
6 | 376.770 | 0.001 | 376.771 |
7 | 376.904 | 0 | 376.904 |
8 | 376.878 | 0 | 376.878 |
9 | 376.943 | 0.004 | 376.947 |
10 (Case C) | 376.940 | 0 | 376.940 |
As shown in
The figures in the first row correspond to Case A. The direct revenue of sellers from the DAM in Case A is 376.057 M€ in total, whereas the side-payments amount to 0.136 M€. The total revenues in Case A amount to 376.193 M€, thus the side-payments represent only 0.036%. In Case C (last iteration), there are no side-payments. The total revenue of sellers reach 376.940 M€, which is higher than that in Case A by 0.747 M€ (0.198%). This is because the iterative process of Case C leads to the exclusion of several PAOs and orders not fulfilling their MIC, thereby incurring an increase in MCPs which outweighs the side-payments of Case A. Overall, Case A leads to lower costs for the end-consumers.
Finally,

Fig. 9 Sensitivity analysis on eligibility threshold X and number of opportunities Y in Case C. (a) X. (b) Y.
This paper addresses two main issues that concern the market participants in European DAMs, namely the feasibility of the attained schedules and the non-confiscation of the cleared volumes.
In order to address the first issue, resource-specific orders have been developed, i.e., THOs, DROs, and ELOs. The enhanced scheduling of the resources when using the new order types has been identified in the results. While the block orders do not always respect the operating constraints of a thermal generating unit and they are not flexible enough to adjust to the hourly load requirements, the proposed THOs provide for a typical start-up/normal dispatch/desynchronization process, respecting other thermal unit constraints such as the minimum up/down time. Regarding the DROs, it is shown that main operating constraints are satisfied, such as a minimum and a maximum delivery period, a minimum baseload period, or a given frequency of activations in the course of a day. Similarly, the results show that the ELOs respect the discharging/charging capability of a storage asset, the state of charge constraints, and the total discharging/charging limitation within a trading day. In that respect, the European legislation should promote the introduction of resource-specific orders in the DAM clearing of the internal electricity market. Notably, the computational complexity of the benchmark European DAM model in the presence of the new order types has been assessed, and the execution time is within the European standards.
To address the second issue, a comparative analysis has been performed between two pricing schemes that ensure non-confiscation: discriminatory pricing with side-payments and non-discriminatory pricing excluding out-of-money orders (the prevalent scheme in European markets). The results indicate that the former scheme exhibits certain advantages: ① the derived revenues of the sellers, which shall be borne by the buyers and eventually by the end-consumers, are lower; ② the make-whole payments to the sellers represent a small portion of their total revenues; ③ no iterative process employing revenue-constrained controls is required (as in the second pricing scheme), thereby the market solution is more stable in terms of cleared volumes and prices.
Future research will investigate and compare the above two pricing schemes with the case of non-discriminatory pricing, where uplift payments are directly included in the market clearing. Convex hull pricing and extended locational marginal pricing shall be investigated to reduce side-payments. Additionally, THOs shall be introduced in more bidding zones to assess the computational burden. Finally, the approach will be tested with a flow-based transportation model (c.f. ATC-based model used in this paper), which is gradually being implemented in the European region.
Nomenclature
Symbol | —— | Definition |
---|---|---|
A. | —— | Sets and Indices |
—— | Step of supply order or demand order | |
—— | Exclusive group of block orders in bidding zone z | |
—— | Step of start-up process of thermal order | |
—— | Index of interconnection | |
—— | Set of interconnections subject to ramping restrictions on power flow variations between succesive hours | |
—— | Order submitted to bidding zone z, where , denotes demand orders; denotes supply orders; denotes block orders (, denotes linked block orders); denotes thermal orders; denotes demand response orders; and denotes energy limited orders | |
—— | Orders subject to load gradient condition | |
—— | Orders subject to the minimum income condition | |
—— | Index of hourly period, where , includes the 24 hourly trading periods, includes the hours preceding the first trading period | |
—— | Index of bidding zone | |
B. | —— | Parameters |
, | —— | Elements of incidence matrices denoting if orders so and bo belong to bidding zone z |
—— | Elements of incidence matrices denoting if block order bo is linked with linked block order lbo or belongs to exclusive group eg | |
—— | The minimum acceptance ratio of block order bo | |
, | —— | The minimum and maximum available transfer capacities of interconnection l in period t (MW) |
—— | The minimum baseload period of order dro (hour) | |
—— | The minimum and maximum delivery periods of order dro (hour) | |
—— | Daily energy quantities offered by order elo for charging and discharging (MWh) | |
—— | The maximum storage capacity of order elo (MWh) | |
—— | The maximum frequency of activations of order dro in course of trading day | |
—— | Increasing and decreasing gradients of supply order so subject to a load gradient condition (MW/h) | |
—— | Energy inflow of order elo in period t (MWh) | |
—— | Load pickup and drop rates of order dro (MW/h) | |
—— | Parameter denoting that interconnection l starts from bidding zone z (equal to 1) and ends to bidding zone z (equal to -1) | |
—— | Large constant | |
—— | Cycle efficiency of order elo | |
—— | Price-quantity pair of order o (€/MWh, MWh) | |
—— | The minimum and maximum offered quantities of order o (MWh) | |
—— | Energy level of step f of start-up process of thermal order tho (MWh) | |
—— | Ramp up and down rates of thermal order tho (MW/h) | |
—— | Ramp up and down limits of net position for bidding zone z in period t (MW/h) | |
—— | Ramp up and down limits of power flow in interconnection l and period t (MW/h) | |
—— | Start-up cost of thermal order tho (€/start-up) | |
—— | Synchronization, start-up, and shut-down time of thermal order tho (hour) | |
—— | The minimum up and down time of thermal order tho (hour) | |
, | —— | Variable and fixed terms of supply order so subject to a minimum income condition (€/MWh, €) |
—— | The minimum required daily revenue of order o, where (€) | |
—— | Attained market revenue of order o submitted with a minimum income condition, where (€) | |
—— | Welfare of block order bo (€) | |
C. | —— | Variables |
—— | Dual variable of net position of bidding zone z in period t | |
—— | Dual variables of ramping limitation on net position of bidding zone z in period t | |
—— | Energy level of order elo in period t (MWh) | |
—— | Power exchange in interconnection l in period t (MWh) | |
—— | Net position of bidding zone z in period t (MWh) | |
—— | Cleared quantity of order o in period t (MWh) | |
—— | Cleared quantities of order tho in start-up and shut-down statuses in period t (MWh) | |
—— | Cleared charging and discharging quantities of order elo in period t (MWh) | |
—— | Binary variable representing clearing status of order o | |
—— | Binary variables denoting that order tho is in synchronization, start-up, normal dispatch, and shut-down clearing statuses in period t | |
—— | Binary variables denoting that order elo is in charging and discharging clearing statuses in period t | |
—— | Acceptance ratio of order o | |
—— | Binary variables which are equal to 1 if clearance of an order begins and ends in period t |
References
Directive 2009/72/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council of 13 July 2009 concerning common rules for the internal market in electricity and repealing Directive 2003/54/EC, 2009. [Baidu Scholar]
Commission Regulation (EU) 2015/1222 of 24 July 2015 establishing a guideline on capacity allocation and congestion management, 2015. [Baidu Scholar]
EPEX SPOT. (2022, Aug.). European market coupling. [Online]. Available: https://bit.ly/3wrSYuC [Baidu Scholar]
NEMO Committee. (2022, Aug.). EUPHEMIA public description, 2020. [Online]. Available: https://bit.ly/3qm1yaz [Baidu Scholar]
Price Coupling of Regions. (2022, Aug.). Euphemia performance, 2015. [Online]. Available: https://bit.ly/3u5zXvo [Baidu Scholar]
European Commission. (2022, Aug.). Clean energy for all Europeans package. [Online]. Available: https://bit.ly/3JpG3gF [Baidu Scholar]
European Commission. (2022, Aug.). Study on energy storage–contribution to the security of the electricity supply in Europe. [Online]. Available: https://bit.ly/3CROqz0 [Baidu Scholar]
ENTSO-E. (2015, Nov.). Market design for demand side response, policy paper. [Online]. Available: https://bit.ly/3Ihu6s0 [Baidu Scholar]
C. Batlle, I. Herrero, and P. Rodilla, “Evolving bidding formats and pricing schemes in USA and Europe day-ahead electricity markets,” Energies, vol. 13, pp. 1-21, Sept. 2020. [Baidu Scholar]
EPEX SPOT. (2022, Aug.). EPEX SPOT introduces curtailable blocks and loop blocks on all day-ahead markets. [Online]. Available: https://bit.ly/3N3mvAV [Baidu Scholar]
G. Liberopoulos and P. Andrianesis, “Critical review of pricing schemes in markets with non-convex costs,” Operation Research, vol. 64, no. 1, pp. 17-31, Feb. 2016. [Baidu Scholar]
B. Eldridge, R. O’Neill, and B. F. Hobbs, “Near-optimal scheduling in day-ahead markets: pricing models and payment redistribution bounds,” IEEE Transactions on Power Systems, vol. 35, no. 3, pp. 1684-1694, May 2020. [Baidu Scholar]
A. J. Conejo and R. Sioshansi, “Rethinking restructured electricity market design: lessons learned and future needs,” International Journal of Electrical Power & Energy, vol. 98, pp. 520-530, Jun. 2018. [Baidu Scholar]
S. Harvey. (2022, Aug.). Is the California ISO becoming an uplift market? Pricing, uplift and commitment (presentation), FTI consulting, 2014. [Online]. Available: https://bit.ly/36r10ZY [Baidu Scholar]
Single Electricity Market Operator (SEM). (2021, Nov.). Trading and settlement code, Version 25.0. [Online]. Available: https://bit.ly/3qfonNi [Baidu Scholar]
P. R. Gribik, W. W. Hogan, and S. L. Pope. (2007, Jul.). Market-clearing electricity prices and energy uplift. [Online]. Available: https://hepg.hks.harvard.edu/publications/market-clearing-electricity-prices-and-energy-uplift [Baidu Scholar]
R. P. O’Neill, P. M. Sotkieqicz, and M. H. Rothkopf. (2007, Jul.). Equilibrium prices in power exchanges with non-convex bids. [Online]. Available: http://bear.warrington.ufl.edu/centers/purc/docs/papers/0601_ONeill_Equilibrium_Prices_in.pdf [Baidu Scholar]
E. J. Zak, S. Ammari, and K. W. Cheung, “Modeling price-based decisions in advanced electricity markets,” in Proceedings of 2012 9th International Conference on the European Energy Market, Florence, Italy, May 2012, pp. 1-6. [Baidu Scholar]
NYISO. (2022, Aug.). Motion for permission to implement hybrid fixed block generation pricing rule. [Online]. Available: https://bit.ly/3IvQM88 [Baidu Scholar]
MISO. (2022, May). ELMP III White Paper I R&D report and design recommendation on short-term enhancements. [Online]. Available: https://bit.ly/3JnSyt5 [Baidu Scholar]
A. G. Vlachos and P. N. Biskas, “Balancing supply and demand under mixed pricing rules in multi-area electricity markets,” IEEE Transactions on Power Systems, vol. 26, no. 3, pp. 1444-1453, Aug. 2011. [Baidu Scholar]
L. Meeus, K. Verhaegen, and R. Belmans, “Block order restrictions in combinatorial electric energy auctions,” European Journal of Operational Research, vol. 196, no. 3, pp. 1202-1206, Mar. 2009. [Baidu Scholar]
C. Ruiz, A. Conejo, and S. Gabriel, “Pricing non-convexities in an electricity pool,” IEEE Transactions on Power Systems, vol. 27, no. 3, pp. 1334-1342, Aug. 2012. [Baidu Scholar]
I. Herrero, P. Rodilla, and C. Battle, “Electricity market-clearing prices and investment incentives: the role of pricing rules,” Energy Economics, vol. 47, pp. 42-51, Jan. 2015. [Baidu Scholar]
A. Martin, J. Müller, and S. Pokutta, “Strict linear prices in non-convex European day-ahead electricity markets,” Optimization Methods & Software, vol. 29, no. 1, pp. 189-221, Jan. 2014. [Baidu Scholar]
G. A. Dourbois and P. N. Biskas, “European market coupling algorithm incorporating clearing conditions of block and complex orders,” in Proceedings of 2015 IEEE Eindhoven PowerTech, Eindhoven, Netherlands, Jul. 2015, pp. 1-6. [Baidu Scholar]
A. G. Vlachos, G. A. Dourbois, and P. N. Biskas, “Comparison of two mathematical programming models for the solution of a convex portfolio-based European day-ahead electricity market,” Electric Power Systems Research, vol. 141, pp. 313-324, Dec. 2016. [Baidu Scholar]
D. I. Chatzigiannis, G. A. Dourbois, P. N. Biskas et al., “European day-ahead electricity market clearing model,” Electric Power Systems Research, vol. 140, pp. 225-239, Nov. 2016. [Baidu Scholar]
M. Madani and M. van Vyve, “A MIP framework for non-convex uniform price day-ahead electricity auctions,” EURO Journal on Computational Optimization, vol. 5, pp. 263-284, Mar. 2017. [Baidu Scholar]
R. P. O’Neill, A. Castillo, B. Eldridge et al., “Dual pricing algorithm in ISO markets,” IEEE Transactions on Power Systems, vol. 32, no. 4, pp. 3308-3310, Jul. 2017. [Baidu Scholar]
R. Fernández-Blanco, J. M. Arroyo, and N. Alguacil, “On the solution of revenue-and network-constrained day-ahead market clearing under marginal pricing–Part I: an exact bilevel programming approach,” IEEE Transactions on Power Systems, vol. 32, no. 1, pp. 208-219, Jan. 2017. [Baidu Scholar]
D. I. Chatzigiannis, P. N. Biskas, and G. A. Dourbois, “European-type electricity market clearing model incorporating PUN orders,” IEEE Transactions on Power Systems, vol. 32, no. 1, pp. 261-273, Jan. 2017. [Baidu Scholar]
A. Sleisz and D. Raisz, “Integrated mathematical model for uniform purchase prices on multi-zonal power exchanges,” Electric Power Systems Research, vol. 147, pp. 10-21, Jun. 2017. [Baidu Scholar]
I. Savelli, A. Giannitrapani, S. Paoletti et al., “Introducing block orders in the Italian day-ahead electricity market,” in Proceedings of 2018 15th International Conference on the European Energy Market, Lodz, Poland, Jun. 2018, pp. 1-6. [Baidu Scholar]
I. Savelli, A. Giannitrapani, S. Paoletti et al., “An optimization model for the electricity market clearing problem with uniform purchase price and zonal selling prices,” IEEE Transactions on Power Systems, vol. 33, no. 3, pp. 2864-2873, May 2018. [Baidu Scholar]
I. Savelli, B. Cornélusse, A. Giannitrapani et al., “A new approach to electricity market clearing with uniform purchase price and curtailable block orders,” Applied Energy, vol. 226, pp. 618-630, Sept. 2018. [Baidu Scholar]
L. H. Lam, V. Ilea, and C. Bovo, “European day-ahead electricity market coupling: discussion, modeling, and case study,” Electric Power Systems Research, vol. 155, pp. 80-92, Feb. 2018. [Baidu Scholar]
G. A. Dourbois, P. N. Biskas, and D. I. Chatzigiannis, “Novel approaches for the clearing of the European day-ahead electricity market,” IEEE Transactions on Power Systems, vol. 33, no. 6, pp. 5820-5831, Nov. 2018. [Baidu Scholar]
N. Koltsakis and A. Dagoumas, “Incorporating unit commitment aspects to the European electricity markets algorithm: an optimization model for the joint clearing of energy and reserve markets,” Applied Energy, vol. 231, pp. 235-258, Sept. 2018. [Baidu Scholar]
N. Koltsakis and A. Dagoumas, “Policy implications of power exchanges on operational scheduling: evaluating EUPHEMIA’s market products in case of Greece,” Energies, vol. 11, pp. 1-26, Oct. 2018. [Baidu Scholar]
A. Sleisz, D. Divényi, and D. Raisz, “New formulation of power plants’ general complex orders on European electricity markets,” Electric Power Systems Research, vol. 169, pp. 229-240, Apr. 2019. [Baidu Scholar]
Nord Pool. (2022, Aug.). Ramping. [Online]. Available: https://bit.ly/3JqXFc0 [Baidu Scholar]
R. P. O’Neill, P. M. Sotkiewicz, B. F. Hobbs et al., “Efficient market-clearing prices in markets with non-convexities,” European Journal of Operational Research, vol. 164, pp. 269-285, Jul. 2005. [Baidu Scholar]
ENTSO-E. (2022, Mar.). Transparency platform. (2022, Aug.). [Online]. Available: https://bit.ly/3EbP50U [Baidu Scholar]
I. G. Marneris, A. V. Ntomaris, P. N. Biskas et al. TestCase. [Online]. Available: https://bit.ly/3KWfGiH [Baidu Scholar]
Hellenic Energy Exchange. (2022, Aug.). Market data & publications. [Online]. Available: https://bit.ly/3RMPkCZ [Baidu Scholar]