Abstract
In recent years, rumors have been shown to have a significant impact on individual and societal activities. As renewables play an increasingly significant role in electricity markets, certain rumors may deviate the bidding behavior of market entities and eventually affect the performance of market operations. In this study, we attempt to reveal the general threats caused by rumors in the context of day-ahead electricity markets considering the integration of volatile renewables. First, we model the propagation of rumors in the societal system considering the weight of propagation resistance, which principally reflects the communication accessibility of market entities. Second, we develop an integrated two-layer network model to uncover the inherent coupling mechanism between market operations and rumor propagation. In particular, the role of electricity market operations on rumor propagation is characterized by changes in the truthfulness of rumors associated with electricity prices. The rumors, in turn, affect the bidding quantities of market entities in electricity market operations. Finally, numerical experiments are conducted on modified IEEE 6-bus and 118-bus systems. The results demonstrate the potential threats of rumors to electricity market operations with different penetration levels of renewables.
THE development of electricity markets and integration of volatile renewables such as wind and solar energy are the two major reforms that all modern power systems have experienced. As it is common for electricity markets to guarantee a higher priority to dispatch renewables, the generation-side uncertainty and volatility resulting from an ever-increasing penetration of renewables may have a significant impact on the pricing of electricity services supplied to customers. Simultaneously, modern power systems are more closely coupled with societal systems, and such couplings further complicate power system operation. For example, the Indian government called on citizens to light candles to pray for the end of the COVID-19 pandemic, which caused considerable challenges to the Indian power system by creating an enormous load drop (about 32 GW) [
In addition to prevailing attacks such as false data injection [
Some researchers have already examined the mutual influence of power and societal systems. Reference [
Meanwhile, with the implementation of Internet-of-Things technologies and advanced data analytics, customers are empowered to regulate their electricity usage patterns in response to the changes in electricity pricing. When allowed to participate in the day-ahead electricity market, the power consumption schedules of customers become more sensitive to the forecasted market-clearing prices. However, consumers commonly have a reduced capability to identify rumors compared to generation companies. Accordingly, customers are particularly susceptible to rumors, and are subject to the implications of rumors in determining their bidding behaviors. That is, the rumor propagation may reshape the performance of electricity market operation and leave consequences on both the power and societal systems, as shown in

Fig. 1 Couplings between power and societal systems.
A high penetration of renewables entering the electricity market may affect pricing regularity, which provides the soil for breeding the rumors related to electricity markets. Rumors may utilize the uncertainty of electricity prices to mislead consumers’ bidding behavior. Some studies have investigated rumor propagation in societal systems. Reference [
To the best of our knowledge, there are few studies pertaining to the impact of rumor propagation on the operation of electricity markets. Provided that the threat of rumors needs to be urgently investigated in electricity markets with the increasing penetration of volatile renewables, the technical work in this study includes the following main contributions.
1) After classifying the potential sources and types of market-oriented rumors, the couplings between rumor propagation and market operations are investigated and analyzed.
2) An integrated and systematic approach is developed from a two-layer complex network perspective to quantify the impact of rumors on market operation performance.
3) The vulnerability of prevailing market-clearing mechanisms to rumors is revealed via a series of numerical simulations with varying penetration levels of renewables.
The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section II states the types of rumors pertaining to electricity markets and presents the rumor propagation model in the context of electricity markets. Section III models the market-clearing by considering the rumor impacts from a two-layer network perspective, and proposes a mechanism for simulating the interaction between rumor propagation and electricity market operation. Section IV analyzes the results of numerical experiments. Finally, Section V draws the conclusions.
In this section, we characterize the types of rumors pertaining to the electricity markets and propose a rumor propagation model considering the operation of electricity markets.
Rumors pertaining to electricity markets are classified as indirect or direct rumors based on their relevance to electricity market operations.

Fig. 2 Classification of rumors pertaining to electricity markets.
As for the content of rumors, they may contain specific content such as the specific time, specific location, and specific market entity. Rumors with specific time mean that there is clear time information in the contents. For example, “the electricity price will increase during 7-9 p.m. on 1
Considering the social and physical properties of electricity markets, the electricity market is modeled as a two-layer network, including the power system layer and the societal system layer, as shown in

Fig. 3 Modeling of power and societal systems as a two-layer network.
The propagation of rumors between market entities is also modeled as a complex network for the societal system layer, which essentially reflects the relationship of information sharing between market entities. In detail, nodes in the network are the entities at the same location as the power system buses, implying that the nodes in the societal system layer have the same geographic properties as the buses in the power system layer. However, unlike power systems, information can flow efficiently on the Internet via social networking applications, e.g., WeChat, Twitter, and Facebook. Accordingly, even for nodes that are geographically distant and not connected by power lines, rumors can still propagate between them; therefore, it is likely to be an edge between each pair of nodes in the societal system layer.
Meanwhile, a high penetration of volatile renewables poses challenges to the secure operation of power systems and introduces significant uncertainty to electricity market management. Moreover, various types of rumors may cause frequent disturbances to the societal system layer and eventually pose risks to market operations. Market entities that believe in rumors may deliver false supply and demand information to other entities which change their bids simultaneously. For instance, if rumors concerning “electricity price will increase sharply” propagate in an area, the related market entities may reduce their bidding quantity, which further exacerbates the challenges to the operation of electricity markets under volatile renewables-based generation.
The SIS model was originally proposed to study the propagation of infectious diseases. In the SIS model, the nodes in the “S” state denote those who are susceptible to the infectious disease but have not been infected yet, and the nodes in the “I” state denote those who have already been infected with the disease. Moreover, those infected with infectious diseases (nodes in the “I” state ) may return to susceptible people (nodes in the “S” state ) after treatment, and vice versa. The traditional modeling of the rumor propagation process resembles the SIS model [
In the traditional SIS model, the propagation and recovery rates are assumed identical for all nodes and do not change with time. However, the possibility of individual market entities to believe in and propagate rumors is different and varies with the rumor propagation process. Accordingly, the possibility of believing in and doubting rumors should not be constant. Based on the traditional SIS model, we introduce electricity market-SIS (EM-SIS) as an integrated model of electricity market operations and rumor propagation. In particular, to better characterize the rumor propagation between market entities, we model the state changes of each node as follows.
For the
(1) |
where k is the occurrence number of rumors; is the set of nodes that are in the “I” state; is the set of nodes that are in the “S” state; is the rumor propagation rate of node j, which is in the “I” state; and is the element of the network adjacency matrix. If , then there is an edge between nodes i and j, and if , then there is no edge between nodes i and j. The transition of node states from “I” to “S” is simply denoted as , and the probability of this progress is calculated as:
(2) |
where is the recovery rate of node j, which belongs to the “I” state.
We further consider the coupling of rumor propagation and electricity market operations. For each market entity, the probability of believing in a rumor is related to the truthfulness of rumors with the locational fact. Mathematically, for node j, the rumor propagation rate and recovery rate are calculated as:
(3) |
(4) |
where is a hyperparameter that measures the impact of the truthfulness of rumors on the propagation rate; and are the propagation and recovery rates of node j at the time of last rumor occurrence, respectively; and is the truthfulness of last rumor, i.e., “high price”, for node j, which is calculated as:
(5) |
where is the locational marginal price at node j in the last occurrence; and is the reference value of the electricity price level that is set to estimate whether the price is high or low so as to measure the trustfulness level of the “high price” rumors. The reference value can be set based on practical experience or investigation. Accordingly, takes a value in the range of [-1,1], and the truthfulness level of rumors is limited when the electricity price is twice higher than the reference value. For a rumor of “high electricity prices across the system”, if , the rumor is regarded by node j as a successful prediction and then believed in; if , the rumor is regarded as fake and screened out. Although the trustfulness level of rumors depends on the locational fact, the content of rumors does not need to be false to have a considerable impact on the electricity market operation. In reality, the threat of rumors relates to the resulting sudden and simultaneous changes in the bidding behaviors of market entities.
Furthermore, the information sharing intensity between market entities is linked to their geographical locations. For instance, market entities have relatively less resistance to sharing information when they are geographically closer, whereas those that are geographically farther away have relatively more resistance to sharing information. Thus, we model a fully connected network with weighted edges to enrich the rumor propagation process. The weight of the edges between nodes i and j is denoted as the attenuation rate of rumors, as calculated by:
(6) |
where is the geographic distance between nodes i and j; and are the maximum and minimum values of the geographic distance set, respectively; is the set of nodes; and is the upper limit of the weight of edges. With a weighted network, the rumor propagation rate can be modified from (1) to (7), which indicates that can better reflect the diversity of the propagation resistance in the societal system layer.
(7) |
In this section, we develop a market clearing model for day-ahead electricity market operations under the influence of rumors and illustrate the mechanism of interaction between rumor propagation and electricity market operation.
Inspired by the investigations presented in [
(8) |
where is a hyperparameter that reflects the relationship between the propagation rate and the reaction of consumers’ behaviors to rumors; and and represent that consumer d is at and not at node j, respectively. It is reasonable that the bidding decisions made by consumers who believe in and propagate rumors with a higher probability are more consistent with the rumor content.
For the detailed setting of in (8), if the rumor is related to “high price,” then the value of is in the range of [-1, 0], i.e., the consumer will decrease the bidding quantity; if the rumor is related to “low price”, then the value of is in the range of [0, 1], i.e., the consumer will increase the bidding quantity. A larger absolute value of represents a more radical reaction of consumers as a response to believing in the rumor. For example, if a rumor mentions “electricity price will increase sharply”, is set as 0.1, the propagation rate is 0.6, and the original bidding quantity is 10 MW. The actual bidding quantity is calculated as MW. Thus, the bidding quantity of consumer d is reduced by 6% as a result of the rumor.
Following the assumptions, the goal of electricity market operation is to minimize operational costs [
(9) |
where is a function that quantifies the cost of dispatching thermal units g at time t; and is the generation amount of thermal unit g at time t.
The system-wide power balance constraint is as follows:
(10) |
where is the dual variable of this constraint at time t; is the committed generation amount of wind farm w; and is the bidding quantity of consumer d at time t, which is calculated as:
(11) |
where T is the set of specific time periods; and is the original power demand, i.e., the bidding quantity without the influence of rumors, of consumer d at time t.
The generation range of thermal units is restricted as:
(12) |
where and are the maximum and minimum outputs of thermal unit g, respectively. In addition, the limitation of the wind generation amount is determined as:
(13) |
where is the predicted generation of wind farm w at time t.
Thermal units are also subject to technical limitations on the ramping rates as follows:
(14) |
(15) |
where and are the maximum values of the upward and downward ramping rates of thermal unit g, respectively.
The transmission capacity of power lines is restricted by:
(16) |
(17) |
where and are the dual variables of the corresponding constraints; is the maximum transmission capacity of line l; is the shift factor of bus i to line l; means that thermal unit g is located at bus i; means that the wind farm w is at bus i; and means that the consumer d is at bus i.
Moreover, to guarantee that the power system has sufficient capacity to tolerate uncertain fluctuations caused by renewables-based generation units and loads, system-wide reserve rates are restricted by (18) and (19), which can be further linearized into (20) and (21).
(18) |
(19) |
(20) |
(21) |
where and are the auxiliary variables that denote the upward and downward spinning reserve capacities of thermal unit g at time t, respectively; and and are the required upward and downward spinning reserves across the power system, respectively.
After solving the proposed optimization model (9)-(17), (20), and (21), we can obtain the locational marginal price for bus i at time t as:
(22) |
We present a simple example to better illustrate the rumor propagation process, as shown in

Fig. 4 Illustration of interactions between rumors and electricity markets.
Herein, we suppose three market entities exist in the system. Initially, the rumor of “electricity prices will increase sharply” propagates in the market, and two out of three market entities eventually believe in the rumor, as shown in stage 1 in
In addition to the locational/spatial coupling of rumor propagation and electricity market clearing, we perform a time-domain simulation for a series of similar rumors that occur in sequence, i.e., the temporal evolution of market entities’ reactions to rumors. In particular, we perform a complete round of market-clearing simulation based on the eventual distribution of the nodes in the “I” state related to a certain rumor (instead of the detailed propagation dynamics of that rumor). The simulation steps for a series of similar types of rumors occurring in sequence are shown in

Fig. 5 Flowchart of modeling of rumor propagation in electricity markets.
In addition, only market entities in the “I” state concern about the truthfulness of rumors, and those who are in the “S” state do not pay attention to the deviation of rumors with facts. Accordingly, the changes of rumor propagation and recovery rates are only associated with nodes in the “I” state. Based on these characteristics, we construct a memory mechanism, in which nodes can memorize the previous values of propagation and recovery rates. For example, although a node in the “S” state would not be directly affected by rumors, it still retains the previous propagation rate to propagate rumors once it suddenly believes in rumors again, i.e., turns to a node in the “I” state.
In this section, we use two representative IEEE test systems [
The modified IEEE 6-bus system is illustrated in

Fig. 6 Modified IEEE 6-bus system and coupled rumor propagation network.
To observe the impact of the market-clearing price on the rumor propagation related to electricity market, we conduct a set of controlled experiments with and without consideration of the electricity price effects. The initial values of propagation and recovery rates are set to be 0.3 and 0.1, respectively. is set to be 0.1, is set to be -0.1, and is set to be 17.51 $/MW.

Fig. 7 Evolving process of nodes in “S” and “I” states. (a) Without consideration of truthfulness. (b) Only considering truthfulness (c) Considering both truthfulness and change of bidding behaviors.

Fig. 8 Evolving process of propagation and recovery rates of nodes. (a) Without consideration of truthfulness. (b) Only considering truthfulness. (c) Considering both truthfulness and change of bidding behaviors.
To observe the indirect impact of bidding behaviors on the propagation of relevant rumors, we conduct a set of controlled experiments with and without consideration of the impact of the bidding behaviors as responses to rumors, respectively.
As shown in
To observe the interaction between rumor propagation and electricity market operation in a larger and more complicated system, we implement numerical simulations in a modified IEEE 118-bus system. The total installed capacity of wind power generation is 1463 MW, where each wind farm with a capacity of 209 MW is located on buses 3, 6, 12, 37, 56, 72, and 112. The initial values of the propagation and recovery rates for all nodes are set to be 0.3 and 0.1, respectively. and are set to be 0.2 and -0.1, respectively. One hundred scenarios are considered in which wind power generation and loads are randomly sampled from 100 wind power generation curves and 100 load curves. The load curves are 1.5 times the actual total load of SE4 which is one of the bidding areas in Sweden from January 1 to April 9, 2020. The realistic generation amounts of Elia-connected onshore wind farms from January 1 to April 9, 2020 are doubled to form the wind power generation curves, which are used as the baseline levels of wind power generation. To observe the impact of different penetrations of renewables-based generation on electricity market, we set three scale factors, , , and , which are 1.0, 1.5, and 2.0 times the base wind power generation, respectively. As shown in

Fig. 9 Rumor propagation network for IEEE 118-bus system.

Fig. 10 Total standard deviations of average LMP with different scales of wind power generation.

Fig. 11 Evolving process of nodes in “S” and “I” states in three cases. (a) ρ=1.0. (b) ρ=1.5. (c) ρ=2.0.

Fig. 12 Evolving process of propagation and recovery rates of nodes in three cases. (a) ρ=1.0. (b) ρ=1.5. (c) ρ=2.0.
To quantify the impact of rumor propagation on the electricity market, we count the total changes in electricity prices, bidding quantities of consumers, and wind power curtailments of all nodes in each market-clearing round with and without rumor propagation, respectively. The market-clearing results without the impact of rumors are regarded as reference values; thus, the threat of rumors can be reflected by comparing the market clearing results with the reference values in the normal case.
As shown in Figs.

Fig. 13 Evolving process of impacts of rumor propagation on changes of electricity prices, bidding quantities, and wind power curtailments of all nodes. (a) Electricity prices. (b) Bidding quantities. (c) Wind power curtailments.

Fig. 14 Total changes of electricity prices, bidding quantities, and wind power curtailments of all nodes due to rumor propagation. (a) Electricity prices. (b) Bidding quantities. (c) Wind power curtailments.
As shown in Figs.
Furthermore, we perform numerical experiments to explore how countermeasures mitigating rumor propagation influence the impact of rumors on electricity markets. Assume that all market entities are trained to improve their ability to identify rumors, which corresponds to an increase in the recovery rate and a decrease in the propagation rate in the EM-SIS model. In the case study of the IEEE 118-bus system, we select the case of and adjust the initial propagation and recovery rates of all nodes to 0.15 and 0.12, respectively, and perform 100 simulations.

Fig. 15 Evolving process of impacts of countermeasures on number of nodes in “S” and “I” states.

Fig. 16 Impacts of countermeasures on changes of wind power curtailments and total power wind power curtailments. (a) Wind power curtailments. (b) Total wind power curtailments.
In this study, we present an in-depth analysis of the possible impact of rumors related to electricity market, and develop a two-layer network model (EM-SIS) to characterize the couplings of rumor propagation and electricity market operation.
Numerical simulations demonstrate the serious implications of rumor propagation in the context of electricity market operation, particularly with a high penetration level of renewables. To respond the threat of rumors relevant to electricity market operation, we suggest the following measures.
1) Strengthen the training of market entities to improve their ability to identify rumors during information sharing.
2) Enrich the information resources at official platforms for market entities to better verify the truthfulness of potential rumors such as establishing a rumor detection and notification platform for the electricity market.
3) Develop emergency mechanisms for electricity market to improve the inherent capability of market operation against rumors. For example, redo market bidding and clearing when the market operation performance exhibits a significant deviation.
Finally, this study can inspire more interdisciplinary investigations on the interactions between information, society, electricity infrastructure, and electricity markets toward power system modernization.
References
E. B. D. Sengupta. (2021, Jan.). Grid managers seamlessly handles 32 GW fall and rise in demand within 20 minutes on Sunday. [Online]. Available: https://economictimes.indiatimes.com/industry/energy/power/grid-managers-seamlessly-handles-32gw-fall-and-rise-in-demand-within-20-minutes-on-sunday/articleshow/75001499.cms?from=mdr [Baidu Scholar]
S. J. Olexsak and A. Meier, “The electricity impacts of earth hour: an international comparative analysis of energy-saving behavior,” Energy Research & Social Science, vol. 2, pp. 159-182, Jun. 2014. [Baidu Scholar]
A. Abu-Rayash and I. Dincer, “Analysis of the electricity demand trends amidst the COVID-19 coronavirus pandemic,” Energy Research & Social Science, vol. 68, p. 101682, Oct. 2020. [Baidu Scholar]
S. Aoufi, A. Derhab, and M. Guerroumi, “Survey of false data injection in smart power grid: attacks, countermeasures and challenges,” Journal of Information Security and Applications, vol. 54, no. 5, p. 102518, Oct. 2020. [Baidu Scholar]
Electricity Information Sharing and Analysis Center. (2016, Mar.). Analysis of the cyber attack on the Ukrainian power grid. [Online]. Available: http://cred-c.org/sites/default/files/docs/Ukraine-Defense-Use-Case_E-ISAC_SANS_CREDC-IW2016.pdf [Baidu Scholar]
Z. Xin. (2020, Mar.). Power utilities asked to ensure proper supply. [Online]. Available: https://global.chinadaily.com.cn/a/202012/19/WS5fdd5583a31024ad0ba9cc79.html [Baidu Scholar]
Y. Zhang. (2020, Dec.). Shanghai, Guangzhou dispel rumors about power restrictions. [Online]. Available: https://www.yicaiglobal.com/news/shanghai-guangzhou-dispel-rumors-about-power-restrictions [Baidu Scholar]
Y. Xue and X. Yu, “Beyond smart grid–cyber-physical-social system in energy future,” Proceedings of the IEEE, vol. 105, no. 12, pp. 2290-2292, Dec. 2017. [Baidu Scholar]
C. Wang, G. Wang, X. Luo et al., “Modeling rumor propagation and mitigation across multiple social networks,” Physica A: Statistical Mechanics and Its Applications, vol. 535, p. 122240, Dec. 2019. [Baidu Scholar]
W. Liu, X. Wu, W. Yang et al., “Modeling cyber rumor spreading over mobile social networks: a compartment approach,” Applied Mathematics and Computation, vol. 343, pp. 214-229, Feb. 2019. [Baidu Scholar]
H. Zhu, J. Ma, and S. Li, “Effects of online and offline interaction on rumor propagation in activity-driven networks,” Physica A: Statistical Mechanics and Its Applications, vol. 525, pp. 1124-1135, Jul. 2019. [Baidu Scholar]
A. Yang, X. Huang, X. Cai et al., “ILSR rumor spreading model with degree in complex network,” Physica A: Statistical Mechanics and Its Applications, vol. 531, p. 121807, Oct. 2019. [Baidu Scholar]
F. Wang, X. Ge, P. Yang et al., “Day-ahead optimal bidding and scheduling strategies for DER aggregator considering responsive uncertainty under real-time pricing,” Energy, vol. 213, p. 118765, Dec. 2020. [Baidu Scholar]
Y. Zheng, H. Yu, Z. Shao et al., “Day-ahead bidding strategy for electric vehicle aggregator enabling multiple agent modes in uncertain electricity markets,” Applied Energy, vol. 280, p. 115977, Dec. 2020. [Baidu Scholar]
K. Poplavskaya, J. Lago, and L. de Vries, “Effect of market design on strategic bidding behavior: model-based analysis of European electricity balancing markets,” Applied Energy, vol. 270, p. 115130, Jul. 2020. [Baidu Scholar]
M. Mallaki, M. S. Naderi, M. Abedi et al., “Strategic bidding in distribution network electricity market focusing on competition modeling and uncertainties,” Journal of Modern Power Systems and Clean Energy, vol. 9, no. 3, pp. 561-572, May 2021. [Baidu Scholar]
P. Razmi, M. O. Buygi, and M. Esmalifalak, “A machine learning approach for collusion detection in electricity markets based on nash equilibrium theory,” Journal of Modern Power Systems and Clean Energy, vol. 9, no. 1, pp. 170-180, Jan. 2021. [Baidu Scholar]
Y. Du, F. Li, H. Zandi et al., “Approximating Nash equilibrium in day-ahead electricity market bidding with multi-agent deep reinforcement learning,” Journal of Modern Power Systems and Clean Energy, vol. 9, no. 3, pp. 534-544, May 2021. [Baidu Scholar]
L. Zhu, F. Yang, G. Guan et al., “Modeling the dynamics of rumor diffusion over complex networks,” Information Sciences, vol. 563, pp. 240-258, Jul. 2021. [Baidu Scholar]
C. Utama, S. Troitzsch, and J. Thakur, “Demand-side flexibility and demand-side bidding for flexible loads in air-conditioned buildings,” Applied Energy, vol. 285, p. 116418, Mar. 2021. [Baidu Scholar]
L. Zhu and X. Huang, “SIS model of rumor spreading in social network with time delay and nonlinear functions,” Communications in Theoretical Physics, vol. 72, no. 1, p. 15002, Dec. 2019. [Baidu Scholar]
H. Zhao and L. Zhu, “Dynamic analysis of a reaction–diffusion rumor propagation model,” International Journal of Bifurcation and Chaos, vol. 26, no. 6, p. 1650101, Jun. 2016. [Baidu Scholar]
C. Peng, H. Gu, W. Zhu et al., “Study on spot market clearing model of reginal power grid considering AC/DC hybrid connection,” Power System Technology, vol. 44, no. 1, pp. 323-331, Jan. 2020. [Baidu Scholar]
Y. Fu and Z. Li, “Different models and properties on LMP calculations,” in Proceedings of 2006 IEEE PES General Meeting, Montreal, Canada, Jun. 2006, pp. 1-11. [Baidu Scholar]
Y. Fu, M. Shahidehpour, and Z. Li, “Security-constrained unit commitment with AC constraints,” IEEE Transactions on Power Systems, vol. 20, no. 2, pp. 1001-1013, Aug. 2005. [Baidu Scholar]
H. Ye, Y. Ge, M. Shahidehpour et al., “Uncertainty marginal price, transmission reserve, and day-ahead market clearing with robust unit commitment,” IEEE Transactions on Power Systems, vol. 32, no. 3, pp. 1782-1795, May 2017. [Baidu Scholar]
IIT. (2021, Mar.). Index of data Illinois Institute of Technology. [Online]. Available: http://motor.ece.iit.edu/data/ [Baidu Scholar]
Elia. (2021, Feb.). Wind power generation. [Online]. Available: https://www.elia.be/en/grid-data/power-generation/wind-power-generation [Baidu Scholar]
Entsoe. (2021, Feb.). Total load-day ahead total load forecast/actual total load. [Online]. Available: https://transparency.entsoe.eu/load-domain/r2/totalLoadR2/show [Baidu Scholar]